In short, had economists gone public with the caveats, uncertainties, and skepticism of the seminar room, they might have become better defenders of the world economy. Unfortunately, their zeal to defend trade from its enemies has backfired. If the demagogues making nonsensical claims about trade are now getting a hearing – and, in the US and elsewhere, actually winning power – it is trade’s academic boosters who deserve at least part of the blame. Dani Rodrik (2016)
Here is a prediction: Five to ten years from now, scores of economics professors will queue up to get onto the BBC, CNN, NBC (as well as lesser news outlets in Germany, Luxembourg, France, and Switzerland) to tell listeners what the more acute observers among them had been suspecting all along: that the free movement of cheap labour, as well as being bad for innovation, investment and productivity, is fuelling populism in the West. As a consequence, those economists will demand, in the intransigent way that marks out the late convert to a cause, that a new trade policy must be instituted as a matter of utmost urgency. The reason they will be giving will be the same they gave when defending their previous orthodoxy: there is simply no alternative!
I’m not an economist myself, but I have talked to members of that profession more often than I care to admit — mostly professors and journalists, but also the odd chief economist of a major company. As a history professor, I had always assumed, naively as it turns out, that they were less ideological than the member of your average History faculty; more focused on the real life unfolding in front of our eyes; more inclined towards sober analysis in the spirit of John Maynard Keynes: “When the facts change, I change my mind. What do you do, sir?” That dictum must have guided them ever since they entered graduate school. Or so, at least, I believed.
One thing that irritated me was that many of the economists I spoke to appeared to work from a thin canvass of historical and philosophical knowledge. This seemed to make them prone to technocratic thinking, as well as receptive to utopias of human perfection, deficiencies they seemed to wear as a badge of honour. I attributed this to the rigorous science they had chosen to pursue, to the fact that they spent most of their waking hours investigating facts and data. In such a culture, learning new things came with opportunity costs, a concept economists value more than anything else.
Yet the truth could not have been further from my expectations. Many of the economists I talked to only truly came alive when someone challenged their favoured orthodoxy. Not that they agreed on everything, of course. Some insisted that state depth was invariably bad, for example, whereas others wished for a more interventionist state. Some still believed in the rational individual, whereas others began to draw on the latest insights from experimental psychology.
So, there was some detectable variety of intellectual perspective and methodological approach. But on one thing they were all agreed, as though guided by some invisible hand: that open borders and free movement were good. Economically, because it boosted GDP on a universal scale. Socially, because it promoted the cosmopolitan virtues of multiculturalism. After all, we from the affluent West have to help everyone to get out of poverty and become a bit like us: rich, happy, and free to choose between twenty different kinds of mustard. They felt that the critics of globalisation had locked themselves into the waiting room of history — that sad and depressing place, where progress was a foreign word. Whereas they, who had picked up most of their historical knowledge from Yuval Noah Harari, were on the right side of history.
This conviction, although it has by now been falsified many times over, still prevails. A considerable portion of academic economists, along with hundreds of think tanks that self-identify as liberal to the core, would probably continue to take seriously a high-priest of open borders like Ilya Somin. Advocating a democracy based on superhuman reason, and hence purified of history and cultural solidarities, Somin is in effect reviving an old universalist utopia for a 21st-century audience.
Yet even now, in 2025, nearly a decade after Brexit and with Trump back in the White House, such views still carry weight amongst the technocratic Anywheres dominating government, the civil service and academia — at least in the West. Many would probably refuse to even consider having a rethink on globalisation and open borders even now. What are facts, after all, when what is at stake is a superior moral vision, one that can be sold, with profit, as serious theoretical insight.
If we consider the cost of that vision in the here and now, there probably exists no more drastic example than the European Union. And by cost I don’t just mean trade and innovation (where EU countries have fallen behind) but also the legitimacy of democratic politics that underpins social cohesion. Rather than trying to identify the causes of the crisis, the EU’s leadership class is preoccupied with its most blatant symptom: populism. Given the choice between drawing a vital lesson and defending the status quo, it has yet again opted for the latter. Eurocrats are still happy to see immigration and free movement being controlled by the ECJ and the ECHR, rather than by voters.
Among trade experts of global standing, Dani Rodrik has been the lone voice challenging this situation with persistency and intellectual rigour. For more than two decades, the Harvard-economist has argued against the open-border consensus of his peers. Not because he is opposed to liberal economics or has a penchant for national populism, but because he thinks that any decent liberalism must rely on a combination of civic rights and civic duties.
In a book entitled Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy, Rodrik summed up his argument against hyper-globalisation, a summary of which can be found in a short online article published in 2016. In one of its key passages, Rodrik discusses how economists who agreed with him in private would refrain from articulating their honest view in public. One refused to provide an endorsement for the back cover of his book, Has Globalisation gone too far?, for fear of being shunned by his colleagues.
When Rodrik delivered academic papers to highlight the negative consequences of globalisation (for both the West and the countries to which labour was being out-farmed), he often got asked the following question: Would he not worry that his arguments “will be abused and serve demagogues and populists”? The question implies a position that contradicts the ethics of academic independence: namely, that economics teaching at major universities have a duty to lend academic credence to the sort of globalisation that pleases the powerful in politics and business. What some of Rodrik’s colleagues had in effect argued is that, by challenging the consensus on globalisation, he would inadvertently serve the cause of what they called “the barbarians”.
Rodrik’s reply to that supposition was spirited as well as clear: “The implicit premise seems to be that there are barbarians on only one side of the trade debate. Apparently, those who complain about World Trade Organization rules or trade agreements are awful protectionists, while those who support them are always on the side of the angels. In truth, many trade enthusiasts are no less motivated by their own narrow, selfish agendas.” Economists shading their arguments to legitimise what they deemed the liberal-progressive cause were thus favouring, as Rodrik put it, “one set of barbarians over another.”
Is protectionism the solution, as Trump and his administration think it will be for the United States? As Matthew Lynn argued in The Telegraph a few days ago, protective tariffs can be seen as a response to America losing the tech war against China. He claims it is the reason why Elon Musk is so supportive of Trump’s tariff war. For many American and European companies, protective tariffs may offer the only chance of survival. As JD Vance claimed in his speech about the conceits of globalisation, outsourcing enabled China to benefit from network effects, with the value chain now being squeezed from above (with product innovation now taking place outside the US) and below (with the cost of production remaining low).
But while Vance’s diagnosis may be broadly correct, it smacks of the power game by a neighbourhood bully. Besides, tariffs may be no more than a short-term answer to the challenge at hand, which is the relative decline in manufacturing capacity, skill and productivity as a result of hyper globalisation. Protectionism’s main aim is to buy time for major companies, including Tesla, Boeing, and Pfizer. What is more likely than companies innovating and investing while the tariff wall is up, at least according to Lynn, is that “chief executives will simply bank the easy sales” and “some massive bonuses” along the way, without seriously addressing the fundamental problems.
In the end, I decided to ask a friend of mine, a Zurich-based economic historian, for advice. He doesn't feel confident to judge the outcome of the tech war, but remains deeply sceptical about China’s alleged competitive edge. Not that he doubts the country’s manufacturing prowess or ingenuity. But he points out the multiple macro-economic challenges China is facing, each of which has the potential to throw a spanner in the works. This includes a real estate crisis, a deflation crisis, a demographic crisis, and a consumption crisis resulting from depressed wages. The magnitude of these crises isn’t remotely addressed by exporting even millions of electric cars. China, my friend notes, is still caught in an economic model relying on private saving, public investment and above all exports. To become affluent like Japan, South Korea and Taiwan, wages would have to increase. Yet this would damage China’s economic model, at least in the short term. The most pressing question seems to be: how much longer can a state exploit its people to finance the party’s industrial policy that prioritises power over affluence?
But that only means that China may be in trouble, too.
It doesn’t mean that JD Vance has been wrong on globalisation.
Dear Oliver
I read your reflections as a historian, looking to make sense of the fundamental shifts of the present (for the lack of a better word), with a strange mix of fascination and curiosity. They are hard to disagree with, yet they rub hard against my own convictions shaped by the "Fukuyama moment" of the early 1990s. Back then, an entire cohort of young diplomats, free traders and internationalists who religiously believed in the virtues globalisation, inclusive economic growth, sustainable development, evidence-based policymaking and regulation, and above all, a rules-based international order, we were starting our way up through the bureaucracies of our institutions, governments, the World Bank and the IMF, the OECD, the OSCE, the European Commission, and the UN. With the Soviet Union collapsing, China opening, the UN Rio Earth Summit in 1992, the creation of the WTO in 1995, finally replacing the provisional construct of the General Agreements of Tariffs and Trade (GATT). It was for us not the "end of history", but without any doubt in our minds the beginning of a benign phase of peaceful global policy coordination, based on sound economic and financial policy principles (later the "Washington Consensus"). China would join the WTO in 2001, as India had in 1995 and Russia would in 2012.
And around 2000 something changed, but we missed the signals. Yes, we would follow the debate between Joseph Stiegitz and Paul Krugman, both Nobel Prize Winners, as the former departed in protest as the World Bank's chief economist in that year. We thought it was an issue of calibrating globalization when indeed it was a fundamental criticism how to go about structural adjustment in the Asian Financial Crisis of the late 1990s, that you cannot mechanically insist on agreed macro indicators when you leave the populations behind, a mistake later repeated, with dramatic consequences for democratic legitimacy of international institutions and EU cohesion in Greece 2010-11.
We internationalists still celebrated these events, in particular the coordination of goverments and central banks during the Great Financial Crisis, as proof that "the system worked", as the continuation of the "trente glorieuses" under US leadership. And the system did work - although it had begun slow and ground to a halt, the WTO dysfunctional, global poverty alleviation backsliding.
But more importantly we were so focused on global development, the creation of transboundary legal and regulatory frameworks required to keep the system up, that we missed the fundamental collateral damage on the domestic side, the growing estrangement between the bureaucratic elites and the populations purported to benefit from them, between the government and the governed. It "rhymes" with an argument you made citing Lüthy's analysis of institutional centralization without cultural integration. We created highly intricated regulatory spaces crossing borders disregarding cultural identity spaces existentially depending on those borders. Dani Rodrik presented his trilemma "How Far Will Economic Integration Go?" (that democracy, national souvereignty and economic integration are mutally incompatible, you can only always have two out of the three) in 2000.
Rodrik's observation is now becoming painfully obvious with the rise of populism. You are working hard to re-define populism as a desperate, often unarticulate and misguided, but ultimately healthy corrective against the runaway-elites, a populism that should be integrated into the democratic process. The downright hatred of the bureaucratic "big government" machine, disconnected from the base, has reached particularly outsized proportions in the US. Globalization and its breaking up of value-chains, the loss of manufacturing jobs combined with dismal social policies and a near-total lack of mechanisms of up-skilling the labor force have left entire swaths of the country behind, disentchanted and angry - and ready to take political revenge. Angus Deaton wrote a ravaging analysis of this phenomenon ("Deaths of Despair and the Future of Capitalism"). You may also want to listen to Peter Thiel in his conversation with Bari Weiss (Youtube: "Peter Thiel on the Triumph of the Counter-Elites").
At lest four questions remain for the future:
1.
Will liberal democracy survive in a time when some Western governments (US, Hungary, Israel, Turkey) succeed in at least partly demantling checks and balances established precisely to hold in check the Jacobines from running with a mandate of the people ("impeach the judges")?
2.
Can we still go about making government more efficient (badly needed: listen to Musk/DOGE on the mine - yes: mine - in Pennsylvania where social security documents are physically stored since the 1950s) without tearing government services apart?
3.
Can the industrialised production of useful multilateral norms (of which I am still a great adherent) be continued in an amenable manner, but communicated in a useful way despite the fact that they reign in sovereignty and the threaten the social fabric? Or will we see continuation to the end of the alternative (the "law of the powerful" instead of a "powerful law")?
The irony of the last point should not be neglected: The same forces that started taming imperialism and unregulated capitalism through the Bretton Wood set of institutions in 1944, for the benefit of the international community (particularly smaller nations) have now created a reasonable probability of a backlash to pre-WWII times.
So all this actually to just say: No, JD VAnce was not right:-)
Stefan
Ich habe den Text von ChatGPT “übersetzen” lassen; Interessant dass der zweitletzte Satz überhaupt nicht berücksichtigt wurde und ChatGPT eine ziemlich eigenwillige Zusammenfassung “kreiert”.
Bedeutet das, dass Protektionismus die Lösung ist, wie Trump und seine Regierung es für die USA sehen? Matthew Lynn argumentierte vor wenigen Tagen im Telegraph, dass protektionistische Zölle als Reaktion auf Amerikas Niederlage im Tech-Krieg gegen China betrachtet werden könnten. Seiner Meinung nach ist dies der Grund, warum Elon Musk Trumps Handelskrieg so sehr unterstützt. Für viele amerikanische und europäische Unternehmen könnten Schutzzölle die einzige Überlebenschance sein.
Doch das bedeutet nicht unbedingt, dass JD Vance in seiner Globalisierungskritik unrecht hatte.